|
So
who gained the estate, plus further over-distribution at later
policyholders’ expense?
-
Besides
saying how the money may have disappeared, Lord Penrose has also
indicated where and when it did so.
Professor Smith’s presidential statement in the 1992 accounts
includes: ”… The fundamental philosophy is that each generation of
policies should receive benefits commensurate with the earnings
produced during its lifetime. Beyond
the bounds of normal commercial prudence, it would be alien to our
culture to hold back benefits from one generation to build reserves
for a future generation. As
we say in our literature, for new policyholders future bonuses must
depend primarily upon the earnings produced on the investments of the
new premiums. Any deliberate cross subsidies between generations would
not be “equitable”. Lord
Penrose comments: “As
appears frequently in these documents, there was an inherent
contradiction in the statement. If
nothing was held back for the future, any over-allocation had to be
recovered from the future. That
had to involve deliberate anticipatory cross-generational subsidy and
to be, in these terms, ‘inequitable’” (P chap 4.82-3, my
italics; see also EARW p7). Did
Professor Smith know this?
-
A more
detailed account of cross-generational subsidy is given in chap
6.71-3. Lord Penrose
explains: “…While the split between GIR, reversionary bonus and
final bonus might vary depending on the policy structure, the same
total return was credited to accumulated policy values regardless of
duration. This contrasted
with the practices of many other companies with significant amounts of
single premium business, where more flexible bonus systems allowed for
variation according to duration in-force and financial experience over
the relative periods. This
flexibility allowed inter-generational smoothing and enabled the
company to avoid locking in to payout patterns in the way the Society
did” (¶ 71). And:
“More generally, it is unclear on what basis the Society
could ever have expected to have been able to operate without
inter-generational transfers in the absence of flexibility to
differentiate by duration. In
With Profits Without Mystery it was acknowledged that each
generation of maturing policies was dependent on capital provided by
succeeding generations. Flexibility to differentiate by duration would
have been necessary for such a system to operate fairly in the absence
of an inherited estate. The
Society’s practice did not provide that flexibility, and, given its
full distribution policy, over-payment on older duration policies was
the direct result” (¶ 73).
This, then, was a crucial piece of knowledge for
better-informed policyholders or groups if they wished fully to
exploit product flexibility, and the availability of total policy
values from 1987 onwards. It
also seems fair to assume that few individual members without access
to well-connected financial advice would have known this.
-
With
this explanation in mind it is also instructive to look at PR Table
6.13, which shows the effect of accumulation in policy value alone or
as a percentage of asset share, and of the different categories of
bonus within policy value. It covers the years 1980 to 2000, and it
illustrates how terminal bonus becomes the dominant element over time.
Table 6.16 is a similar breakdown, but based on asset share per
£1000 invested annually over the same period, and it paints a broadly
similar picture. Unfortunately however, these tables do not go back
far enough to cover the whole of the critical period spanning
dispersal of the Society’s estate.
Interestingly, however, there is a table of terminal bonus
accumulation over the 35 years preceding 1999, albeit expressed as a
percentage of all the guaranteed elements. It forms part of Society
leaflet (45J099 WP/UL 2.99) entitled:
“Pension and Life Assurance Plans. Annual Statements- Further
Information”. When
plotted as in the figure below, the data show that the biggest
relative annual terminal bonus additions were made over the 1973-86
period, i.e. that spanning the dispersal of the estate during which
Barry Sherlock was the Appointed Actuary and subsequently Managing
Director. This was also the period of steepest relative accumulation
rate of terminal bonus. The graphs also indicate how much terminal bonus was
awarded retrospectively to policies in force during the decade prior
to its introduction in 1973.
NB:
The cumulation profile illustrated is relative to the guaranteed
elements of individual asset share and guaranteed bonus cumulation (the
cumulation of which is also important for determining the absolute
amount of asset share, which in turn depends upon individual contribution
history). It assumes a constant level of annual contribution, but, given
the structure of the fund, suitably informed policyholders might have done
well to increase their later contributions, which they could do up to a
maximum tax allowance limit. They
would also then have had to crystallise their gains at an appropriate and
advantageous time; later policyholders whose policies had more time to run
were perforce left exposed, and had also to meet the costs of previous
over-distributions. After
1985/6 the real glory days of terminal bonus and potentially
crystallisable gain were over. From the sales point of view it all
looked very impressive, and so it is not surprising that the senior
management team wished to carry these figures over to support an extended
fund in 1987. The prospect of
such performance continuing on the same basis was, however, entirely
without foundation, such that the use of these prior performance figures
was inappropriate, un-representative, and
misleading.
-
The
beneficiaries of “deliberate anticipatory cross-generational
subsidy”, who received the rump of the estate and more between 1973
and 1987, were thus longer duration policyholders who were selectively
favoured (P3.46, 51, 60, 74, 94, 103, 109, 112, 129, 144, 145 items 5
& 8, 152, 161 & 168; P4.16 &36; 14.68).
And since the GAR option was withdrawn for policies begun after
1988, this group was also essentially comprised of longer-term GAR
policyholders. Moreover
after 1987, “The
advertisement of “policy value” to members who had reached an age
at which it was open to them to take their benefits allowed those with
the financial acumen or appropriate advice to elect for an early
maturity date and crystallise their benefit entitlement at an unduly
high value to the disadvantage of continuing members.
In the early 1990’s, this was facilitated by new flexible
products developed by the Society” (P4.29).
The implications of this are serious, and the more so if
they involved fund switching.
-
One
reason for the selective bonus allocation to policies of particular
durations was said to be maintenance of the Society’s position in
performance tables, i.e. marketing considerations. But, as explained
in EARW Section 3 p9 et seq., the historical problem was that
established members would resist significant increases in membership
because it diluted their own claims on the estate.
Given the Society’s commitment to expansion and to retain
FSSU members, it would have been politic to forestall this by awarding
longer term members a disproportionate share of the estate. One
must also hope that similar favours were neither sought nor proffered
for inward transfers of longer duration policies during the drive for
expansion.
-
Lord
Penrose summarises some of this as follows: “In 1986 and 1987, the
sums available in investment reserve were supplemented by the
appropriation of general reserves amounting to £4m to massage total
payouts on pension business at sensitive durations, taking the Society
into a position of over-distribution by the end of 1987 at the latest.
Adverse market conditions aggravated the position, and an
excess of aggregate policy values over available assets continued into
1988. In 1989, when there
was a good return, the Society deliberately distributed a high
proportion of the available return for market-related reasons, and
accordingly entered the 1990’s with a negative estate (P4.36)”. But,
as revealed by the above account and graph, this is unlikely to be the
whole story.
-
Depending
upon personal and external circumstances, postponement of retirement
could also achieve the same end.
Consider, for example, Headdon’s explanation of why the
actual results for 1995 had shown payments to policyholders
considerably in excess of those projected for the year.
“ It appears that some clients were delaying retirement until
the managed pension contract became available.
A substantial part of retirement proceeds will, in fact, have
been left with the Society and contributed to the premium income
position…”. In the same paragraph (P4.128) Lord Penrose himself
continues: “The
consequences of the managed pension for policyholders was to become a
significant factor in the closing years of the reference period. Evidence from the independent financial adviser sector
indicates that some at least some of its practitioners appreciated
that it was to the advantage of their clients to take benefits at a
time when policy values were high relative to underlying assets.”
-
These
inequities were complicated by the fact that group pension scheme
trustees were able to delay the withdrawal of GAR policies in 1998,”
insisting on the right to introduce new members to their schemes for a
further five years” (P2.43-4). This would also have made the
introduction of the DTBP a very sensitive issue until the five grace
years were up, which is highly likely to explain why it did not
surface until 1993, even though the need for action of some sort was
increasingly urgent.
If so, it also had the effect of extending the period during
which GAR crystallisable gains could be made with impunity.
For a discussion of the significance of this and related
matters see the “Fat Cats and Poor Mice” section of the Level 2
narrative.
-
Assuming
that they were members of the Society’s pension funds, we may follow
the combined effects of all this on the pension fund contributions of
Sherlock, Ranson, & Headdon.
The PR does not say when Sherlock joined the Society, but that
he retired in 1991. He would have been a contributor for several years
before Ogborn retired, and so would have got all the retrospective
terminal bonus additions as shown in the figure.
He would also have crystallised his gains at full value with
all his fund choice options intact.
Ranson, who joined the Equitable in 1951, would likewise have
accumulated the same terminal bonus as Sherlock. He retired in 1997 after the DTBP had been announced and
implemented, and so assuming he stayed in the w-p fund he would have
had to take the hit if he exercised the GAR option. However, his GAR
in possession would have been at a low rate, such that he might not
have considered himself sufficiently “in the money”. Under the
prevailing circumstances and given his expertise, he may not have
elected to remain in the w-p fund.
Headdon joined in or around 1978.
The figure indicates that his terminal bonus accumulation would
have been approximately 2/3 that of Sherlock and Ranson. However, he would have had a higher GAR in possession.
Even so, at the time of his forced resignation on March 1st
2001 he would have been most unwise to take his benefits from the w-p
fund. Nash’s situation
would presumably have been closer to Headdon’s than Ranson’s-
he resigned on Dec 8th 2000.
No
estate + no un-hypothecated reserves = no smoothing policy…
-
Accordingly,
despite looking, Lord Penrose has found no evidence that any defined
smoothing policy ever existed under the WPWM concept. He summarises:
“There was at no time a statement of the Society’s
smoothing policy. There
was no specification of smoothing parameters, as regards a target line
of equilibrium, deviation above or below any such line, target
durations of any smoothing cycle or any other factor.
The description of the position in the late 1980s as a point on
the smoothing cycle appears to have had no basis in reality.
It would have been possible to consider the restoration of
reserves between 1976 and 1982 as part of a smoothing process if the
parameters had been defined. From
1982 until the end of the decade the Society had progressively
weakened its reserves until a negative position had become established
where policy values intimated in illustrations and on payout exceeded
available assets. If
there had been a smoothing cycle, it was without defined limits of
value, and it was without defined limits of time” (P3.169. See also
P6.22 & 12.121-3.)
…so
how did the Society maintain the semblance of one under circumstances of
chronic over-allocation exacerbated by debt?
-
What
passed for a smoothing policy was expressed rather differently, and to
understand it one must first make a distinction between the mechanisms
the Society used to meet the guaranteed and non-guaranteed portions of
maturing claims. In Lord Penrose’s words:
“Terminal bonus payouts were made out of current year surplus
with the remainder of the actuarially determined surplus being made
available for declared bonus or carried forward.
Consequently the value of a claim would represent a policy’s
aggregate policy value with the guaranteed portion being met by a
reduction in the Society’s liabilities and the non-guaranteed
(terminal bonus) portion being met by a reduction in current year
surplus. This method was
adopted in both the accounts and the return.
The
Society’s ability to account for terminal bonus in this manner
circumvented recognition in any form in either the statutory accounts or
the regulatory return of the balance of the accumulated terminal bonus
accrued on in-force business and intimated to policyholders
(my italics; cf. EARW Section 4: Sophistries of the Second Order Item 3).
Whether or not the Society was under any obligation to account for
the accrued value of such terminal bonus allotments (which gave rise to an
off balance sheet exposure) in either its accounts or returns depends on
meaning and effect of the various reporting requirements discussed
earlier” (P10.78-9). Bluntly, the guaranteed element was booked for
without the backing of a free asset or mismatching reserve, while the
floating terminal bonus element was both taken off the books and “ponzified”,
i.e. allowed to be the first call on the Society’s annual income as
policies successively matured in an uncontrolled, albeit not entirely
unpredictable fashion. Ponzification
of the un-guaranteed element thus became the mainstay of short term
“smoothing”
Thus
informed we can address P12.121-3, which state: “Ernst & Young sent a monthly insurance letter to the
Society. In October 1995 the
letter was entitled “Creeping Insolvency”.
It raised a number of points.
It suggested that non-executive directors of life offices might
want to consider the following issues (my italics):
i.
Not
all the surplus represented by the difference between assets and
liabilities would be available as “free capital”.
ii.
Part
of this surplus would need to meet the cost of terminal bonuses, and the
amount would be determined using assets share techniques.
iii.
It
was, of course, true that until the terminal bonuses were paid, the
relevant funds were available for investment, including investment in new
business (i.e. the so-called “investment reserve” mentioned in the
WPWM paper- MN), but care needed to be taken in matching cash flows,
taking into account the maturity profile of the with-profits portfolios.
iv.
The
non-executive director might therefore ask the Appointed Actuary to
demonstrate the level of free capital after allowing for terminal bonuses
and additional capital required to smooth bonuses.
v.
It
was quite possible that the resulting free capital could be negative,
which would indicate an urgent need to reduce bonus rates and move to a
lower risk investment strategy.
Headdon
responded to Ernst & Young stating:
“I
was very interested in the above newsflash on questions a non-executive
director of a life office might ask the Appointed Actuary.
There was, however, one point, which caused me some concern.
That was the suggestion on page 3 that, if the free capital after
allowing for terminal bonus is negative, that indicates an “urgent need
to reduce bonus rates and move to a lower risk investment strategy”.
If
one considers a with-profits mutual which operates on the “revolving
fund” principle with no estate and which aims for a “full
distribution” policy, then, on average, policy values should be above
underlying asset values half the time.
(They would, of course, be below for the other half of the time.)
For such an office that is what smoothing would mean”
(my italics: see also EARW Section 3: Sophistries of the First Order Items
3-7). Headdon’s
“smoothing” was thus maintenance of total policy value
by means other than more formal reserving, and not by easing any
fluctuations in the annual overall rate of return.
Bannon
(E & Y’s audit actuary John Bannon- MN) replied on 8th
November saying,
“I
agree entirely with the point you make regarding free capital in the
context of a revolving fund principle with no estate”.
He agreed that the sentence quoted by Headdon should therefore be
qualified. He added, “I
have to say I am very much in favour of the “full distribution”
policy, but when I wrote the article I had more in mind those offices
which maintain a cushion of free assets to facilitate smoothing.”
It
is not clear from his reply that Bannon had fully appreciated what Headdon
was saying, and which did not tally exactly with Sherlock’s account of
smoothing in his February 1989 letter to RAP policyholders (P14.71).
Sherlock wrote:” …the benefits under our with-profits policies depend
primarily on the successful investment of the premiums and only marginally
on profit arising from other policies.
Further, we aim to ensure that the total proceeds members receive
reflect the investment returns on the fund during the course of the
policy. However, the
essential nature of with-profits business, namely the steady addition of
declared and, therefore, guaranteed bonuses, means that there is no
automatic link between asset values and policy benefits (which with
hindsight resembles Ponzi by another name-my italics). In simple terms there is a smoothing of asset values over
time and of the peaks and troughs through the bonus system. Although the
with-profits system contains within it an essential element of smoothing,
nevertheless the Society’s practice is to limit that to evening out
peaks and troughs and unduly sharp changes from year to year. Specifically, we do not set out to build up excessive “free
reserves”, which some describe as “strength”.
This could only be done by deliberately, or worse still,
accidentally, withholding part of the return due to members for the
benefit of their successors. What is important is that there should be
sufficient strength to avoid any unplanned constraints on investment
freedom or growth in business (if only it had been so- MN), while still
giving “full value” return to existing members.”
Policyholders would not have welcomed the idea that policy
values were subject to fluctuation from year to year, and would have
understood smoothing in its more normal sense of operating on the annual
rate of return only, and not policy values as well.
And since Lord Penrose stated earlier in the same paragraph that
the hidden DTBP was not mentioned, policyholders would not have known what
else was implicit in the above italicised sentence. Once again the
rest of P 14.68-83 is useful background information, and cf.16-17 above.
These
extracts are of particular interest because they bring so many critical
aspects of the story together, and illustrate why their combination had
such far-reaching effects. They also give an inkling of John Bannon’s
expectations as to the degree of working knowledge that non-executive
directors should have had, but which had not been provided at the
Equitable.
One is also bound move beyond Lord Penrose’s exposition and ask
what hope there could have been for keeping policy values above underlying
asset value even half the time once more debt had been taken on to extend
the original over-allocation. Next,
factor in the belatedly and obscurely disclosed DTBP, and attempt to
reconcile it with the “ponzification procedure” in a climate of good
faith: at which point the edifice finally collapses. In essence, this
is the sophisticated position that eluded directors, E & Y, the F
& IA and the regulators. We should not too readily assume,
however, that individual actuaries and auditors in various branches of
their professions had not suspected or deduced the essence of what was
afoot.
|
|